Cantor & Packer 1997 - differences of opinion and selection bias in the credit rating industry
Samenvatting:
de verschillen in ratings die bureaus geven aan eenzelfde product zijn voornamelijk afkomstig van het feit dat hun ratingschalen (die meestal dezelfde layout hebben) andere indelingen kennen
Nuttige Stukken:
Although a number of other
credit rating agencies with a narrower focus operate in the United States,
DCR, Fitch, Moody's and S&P are the only agencies that rate US corporate
obligations across a broad industry spectrum. For example, Thomson Bankwatch
and IBCA (in the United States) exclusively rate financial institutions and
A.M. Best provides ratings on insurance companies' claims-paying abilities. P3
The
Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) currently designates only Moody's,
S&P, DCR, and Fitch as "nationally recognized statistical rating
organizations" (NRSROs) for rating all US corporate bond issues; 5 the
other regulators rely on the SEC's designations. P4
Many researchers have
documented that third, or optional, agencies on average assign higher ratings
than Moody's and S&P. Our results suggest that observed differences in
average ratings reflect differences in rating scales. They also call into question
financial industry regulations that assume equivalence of rating scales P22
We also explored why firms
choose to obtain additional ratings. We found that firms are more likely to
obtain a third rating if they are large and experienced issuers in the capital
market. However, there is little evidence that third agencies are employed
either to resolve ex ante uncertainty or to clear regulatory hurdles. While the
rating scales of third agencies may be higher than others, there is little
evidence that the decisions of issuers to use them are influenced by that
factor P22
20-07-2009 om 01:13
geschreven door pieter
Stolper 2009 - Regulation of Credit Rating Agencies
Samenvatting:
de verhouding tss CRA's en de regulerende overheden is een principal-agent relatie. Er bestaat een werkwijze van de overheden die voorkomt dat rating agencies samenwerken om verhoogde ratings af te leveren en ze motiveert om correct te werken.
Nuttige Stukken:
This paper studies a repeated principal-agent problem in which a
regulator approves credit rating agencies. While credit rating agencies can
observe an issuers type, the regulator cannot. Credit rating agencies offer
each issuer a rating and are paid by the issuerswho demand a rating. The regulator cannot
observe whether a credit rating agency assigns correct ratings. The regulator
can only observe the default rate within a rating category for each credit
rating agency. The default rate within a rating category does not only depend
on whether a credit rating agency assigns correct ratings. The default rate can
also be influenced by a common shock. P1
The model shows that there exists an approval scheme which can
induce credit rating agencies to offer correct ratings. The model suggests that
a regulator should both deter a credit rating agency from unilaterally offering
inflated ratings, and provide an incentive to deviate from a collusive
agreement to offer inflated ratings. The model indicates that a regulator
should both threaten to deny approval in future periods if a credit rating
agencys performance is worse than its competitors, and reward a credit rating
agency which deviates from a collusive agreement to offer inflated ratings by
reducing the number of approved credit rating agencies in future periods. P5
20-07-2009 om 15:29
geschreven door pieter
Kuhner 2001 - Financial Rating Agencies - Are They Credible
Samenvatting:
...
Nuttige Stukken:
The paper asks if credit rating
agencies have incentives to misrepresent their clients
credit quality during an ongoing
systemic crisis. Two important elements are essential for
a systemic crisis: (1) Investors are
not able to distinguish fundamentally healthy debtors
from fundamentally unhealthy ones.
(2) Investors tend to cumulatively withdraw their
funds. Therefore, neither
fundamentally healthy nor unhealthy debtors can be expected to
survive a
creditors exit. P1
Their goal is to overcome asymmetric information
between
both market sides by evaluating financial claims
according to standardized quality
categories P1
The agencies most important
job is the evaluation of fixed income securities. P2
rating agencies emphasize that their evaluation is,
after
all, their subjective opinion, which is not verifiable
by courts4. Also, damages due
to obvious rating errors are not part of the rating
contract and not currently
enforceable by litigation5. P2
ðenkel reputatie
staat in voor kwaliteit
P3 -> allerlei argumenten
tegen rating agencies
Procyclical bias: Especially in the aftermath of the Southeast Asian
crisis in
1997/1998, agencies were blamed for behaving
procyclically, i.e. for simply following
the majority opinion of market participants13: According to
many
observers, the agencies did not give any warning
signals until after the turbulence
in the Asian markets had begun. However, when the
crisis was actually
spreading, the agencies reacted by cumulatively
downgrading issuers invested
in the Southeast-Asian markets without taking in
account individual portfolio
quality14. P3
Voor de
rest was deze paper te moeilijk!
20-07-2009 om 15:30
geschreven door pieter
Nomura - Fixed Income Research 16/2/2006 - Rating Shopping, now the consequences
Rating Shopping
Defined: Rating shopping occurs when an issuer chooses the rating agency that will assign the highest rating or that has the most lax criteria for achieving a desired rating. Rating shopping rarely involves corporate, sovereign, and municipal bonds. However, it is common for securitization issues.
S&P's Criteria Change: S&P's old criteria for rating CDO's backed by corporate debt included a modeling assumption of zero correlation between companies in different industries.2 That assumption was very lenient and often allowed CDO issuers to achieve their target rating levels with less credit enhancement than the other rating agencies would have required.
=> veel kritiek, alle andere ratingbureaus kwamen met empirisch bewijs dat dat geen nul kon zijn -> S&P verhoogt inter industry correlation van 0 naar 5% => 35 tranches kregen plots negative implications
Conclusion: The implications are reasonably clear. An investor seeking rating stability generally should favor multiple-rated deals. Deals that carry multiple ratings are less likely to carry significant migration risk associated with rating shopping. However, an investor should expect to give up some increment of yield to get securities that carry multiple ratings.
20-07-2009 om 15:37
geschreven door pieter
22-07-2009
BIS working paper no209: FAIR VALUE ACCOUNTING FOR FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS: SOME IMPLEMENTATIONS FOR BANK REGULATION (August 2006)
Samenvatting:
Zowel de FASB als de IASB hebben de laatste jaren standaarden ingevoerd die er op wijzen dat men stelselmatig naar full fair value voor financial instruments wil streven. Intussen gaat dit al niet meer door, dixit de IASB!
Een van de onderzoeksresultaten is: Second, they need to consider more broadly how best to minimise measurement error in fair values so as to maximise their usefulness to investors and creditors as they make their investment decisions, and how best to ensure bank managers have incentives to select those. Om minder measurement errorste hebben past de IASB sinds kort die level-hierarchy toe, maar die stond reeds in FASB exposure draft in 2005! Dus of het effectief zal zijn is maar de vraag natuurlijk...
Market to market implementation issues
Marking-to-market financial instruments are relatively easy if they are actively traded in liquid markets. The problem becomes more complicated if active markets do not exist, particularly if the financial instrument is a compound instrument comprising several embedded option-like features, values for which depend on inter-related default and price risk characteristics. Moreover, Barth and Landsman (1995) makes the observation that in the absence of active, liquid markets, fair value is not well defined in the sense that an instruments acquisition price, selling price, and value-in-use to the entity can differ from each other.13 Stated another way, even if an instruments acquisition or selling prices are observable, these prices can only, at best, provide upper or lower bounds on its fair value. The FASBs stated preference for using an instruments selling price as its measure of fair value is appropriate when fair value is well defined, but is somewhat arbitrary when it is not.
Dus in 1995 is er reeds een paper verschenen die vragen stelt bij het gebruik van fair value in illiquide markten.
Voor de rest gaat de paper vooral over waarom men fair value al dan niet een goede maatstaf is om te meten. Dit is eigenlijk irrelevant voor de thesis, aangezien we fair value als een gegeven beschouwen. De dingen die hierboven staan kunnen wel interessant zijn.
22-07-2009 om 12:06
geschreven door pieter
FEP working papers: the transition to IFRS: disclosures by portuguese listed companies ( august 2008)
Deze paper gaat hoofdzakelijk over de transitie van Portguese GAAP naar IFRS, en dit niet specifiek voor de banksector. Minder interessante paper dus.
Wat wel interessant is: de conservatism index die ze gebruiken om GAAP conservatief gedrag te vergelijken met IFRS. (vanaf p. 16)
Op p.17 staat er een formule die men gebruikt om 'conservatism' te meten. Deze komt uit:
Gray, S. J. (1980), "The impact of International Accounting Differences from a Security-Analysis Perspective: Some European Evidence", Journal of Accounting Research, Vol. 18, 1, pp. 64-76.
We kunnen deze formule misschien toepassen op het verschil tussen IFRS en onderliggend resultaat bij banken, vanaf 2006 bekeken. Wel met de bedenking dat de formule voorzien is voor een hele lijst van ondernemingen binnen een land (niet alleen de banksector). Maar het kan interessant zijn aangezien een groot deel van de verliezen van KBC (en waarschijnlijk ook Dexia) te wijten zal zijn aan IFRS voor financial instruments.
Ook zeker nog te lezen:
Jermakowicz, E. (2004), "Effects of Adoption of International Financial Reporting Standards in Belgium: The Evidence from BEL-20 Companies", Accounting in Europe, Vol. 1, September, pp. 51-70. Jones, T. and R. Luther (2005),