P/E ratio's berekenen voor banken EPS ratio ROE ratio -> indien kapitaalverhoging, gebruik ROAE kijken naar evolutie in operationele resultaten enzo kijken hoeveel ratings KBC producten hebben en van wie (2-rating standard) eerst jaren 07 08 vergelijken en kwartaal 1.
Fratianni & Marchionne 2009 - THE ROLE OF BANKS IN THE SUBPRIME FINANCIAL CRISIS
Samenvatting:
Vooral structured finance (securitization), fair value accounting en errors in judgement van Credit Rating Agencies hebben de crisis gemaakt tot wat ze is op vlak van banken.
Nuttige stukken:
There are some features that are unique to this crisis,
such as the transfer of assets from the balance sheets of banks to the markets,
the creation of complex and opaque assets, the failure of ratings agencies to
properly assess the risk of such assets, and the application of fair value
accounting P3
Two serious problems arise with the practice of structured
finance. The first regards the incentive of the originator to screen debtors
when the loans are destined to be placed off balance sheet. Reputational
considerations would suggest that the originator would not want to compromise
its standards. However, the fact that regulators and accounting standards
required little disclosure about unconsolidated off-balance sheet entities made
these entities opaque to investors and lowered the cost of reputational loss to
the sponsoring institution. P9
Implications of Fair Value accounting: The first is that
unrealized gains and losses impact owners capital. The second is that, like
for any other accounting rule, fair valuation provides incentives to management
to game the rules to boost earnings (or reduce losses) and management bonuses
linked to earnings performance. Thus, during periods of rising asset prices,
the incentives will be to move assets into the trading account categories, and
conversely during declining asset prices. The third is that when markets become
less liquid, valuation models based on internal information become more
relevant than valuation models based on observables and the latter more
relevant than the use of unadjusted quoted prices. In the presence of patently
illiquid markets, an argument can be made that fair values should be based on
reliable estimates of future net cash flows. Finally, the pro-cyclical bias of
fair value accounting tends to magnify current financial trends and,
consequently, exacerbates a financial crisis (Wallison 2008). Lower accounting
asset values that impact on regulatory capital may trigger management to sell
in illiquid markets. P13
Ander bruikbaar materiaal:
Errors
in judgment were as glaring as assigning the same letter grade to a CDO and a
corporate bond with sharply different default rates.6
Calomiris (2007,
p. 19) quotes from the Bloomberg Market of July, 2007 that CDOs rated
Baa by Moody suffered five-year default rates of 24 percent, whereas corporate
bonds with the same rating had default rates of 2.2 percent.
14-07-2009 om 00:00
geschreven door pieter
18-07-2009
Kerwer 2001 Standardising as Governance
Samenvatting:
This paper analyses credit rating agencies as one example
of a private authority involved in the governance of financial markets.
Nuttige Stukken:
These risk assessments are widely used for making
investment decisions in the market place.private credit ratings have been used
to make the regulation of financial market risk sensitive for example by
restricting the investment activities of banks to instruments of low credit risk
P5
rating agencies almost never have to justify their
decisions, let alone provide compensation to others for the adverse
consequences of their mistakes. The breach between the magnitude of potential
damages for borrowers and the possibilities of a remedy gives rise to an
accountability gap. P5
Rating agencies have not been exploiting the informational
asymmetry between themselves and their users. Thereason is that information intermediaries are
seen to be particularly vulnerable to a loss of reputation as credible sources
of information (Mann 1999). Yet, monitoring by reputation can be less effective
in times of financial crisis, when rating agencies start to copy each other in
order to avoid being the only one off the mark (Kuhner n.d.). P7
Second, it is doubtful whether the power of the rating
agencies can be explained solely by the fact that there is no alternative to
their credit risk assessments. In fact, alternative sources of information on
credit do exist, such as credit registers and export credit ratings (Estrella
et al. 2000: 55-125). Beyond that, a wide range of sources exist that produce
credit-related knowledge; for example, investment funds, banks, professional
associations and even academia. P8
the accountability gap is a problem because it prevents
the correction of errors, not because of a hidden ideological agenda P12
As a
rule, the rating of a borrower will not be higher than the rating of the
country of origin. Second, ratings depend on some properties of the borrower
himself. For any typeof firm,
credit-worthiness depends on the ratio of firm value to outstanding debt
(Gordon 1991). The higher the value of a firms assets, the higher the income
flows and the lower all debt obligations, the higher the credit rating is going
to be .assess the stability over time and the likelihood of a declining
performance under stress P13
Rating
agencies and other institutions are not distinguished for publishing their
analyses of credit-worthiness ... The claim is thus that ratings allow a comparison
of the credit-worthiness P14
What is more, rating decisions always have a qualitative
side that is impossible to formalize P15
Since
the regulatory use of ratings seeks to curb excessive risk-taking, it targets
the investors or borrowers .Thus, in order to avoid being excluded from the
credit market, lenders have a strong incentive to observe the rating agencies
standard of credit- worthiness. Thus, in order to avoid being excluded from the
credit market,
lenders have a strong incentive to observe the rating
agencies standard of credit-worthiness.P19
An accountability gap arises whenever there is a breach
between the power of a rule-maker and the possibility to attribute blame. P22
Certainly rating agencies decline any responsibility for
their decisions: they maintain that their information on credit risks cannot
pre-empt financial decision-making but only guide it (McGuire 1991: 83).6 There are a number of good reasons for this
stance. First, investment decisions always have to be related to the entire
portfolio. A security with a low credit rating is not necessarily a bad
investment, since it promises a higher yield. Second, investment decisions
inevitably comprise other risks beyond mere credit risk measured by the credit
rating. Additional risks such as exchange-rate risks with foreign investments
or liquidity risks are not included in a rating. P22
Limited Liability
Limited Competition
Limited Supervision
In times of crisis, changes of credit ratings seem to have
a pro-cyclical effect on the dynamics of financial markets and thus aggravate
rather than stabilise a crisis (Adams et al. 1999: 186). P27
They enable transactions that otherwise would not be
possible (and by so doing they may even have welfare enhancing effects). As
such, they also merit a certain degree of protection. P27
18-07-2009 om 23:20
geschreven door pieter
Gerding 2009 - The Outsourcing of financial regulation to risk models and the global financial crisis
Samenvatting:
De laatste 20 jaar heeft men in de financiële sector teveel gebruik gemaakt van risicomodellen die de realiteit niet kunnen vatten. Daarnaast zijn er ook nog enorm complexe producten ontstaan die soms dubbel verpakt worden. Er is iets fundamenteels mis met de waarderingsmodellen.
Nuttige Stukken:
The widespread use computer-based
risk models in the financial industry in the last two decades enabled the
marketing of more complex financial products to consumers, the growth of
securitization and derivatives, and the development of sophisticated risk
management strategies by financial institutions p1
These risk models failed spectacularly in the global
financial crisis that started in the subprime mortgage market,2 and this outsourcing of regulation exacerbated the crisis. P2
This Article refers to the above software and computer-based
risk models as the new financial code. P4
risk models
make various assumptions in attempting to quantify these probabilities and
often use historic loss data to model future losses. But, attempts to quantify
these probabilities are inherently problematic, because future losses may not
follow historic patterns P11
Credit risk: For a financial institution, credit risk means the
risk that a borrower will default on payment of obligations to that
institution.
Market risk: Market
risk, on the other hand, covers risks that the value of a firms investments or
other assets will decline (or, that its liabilities will increase) due to
changes in market prices.41 A firm and its investment portfolio may be subject
to price fluctuations in different types of markets. Therefore, market risk
includes several different subcategories of risk, including the following:
Interest
rate risk, or the risk exposure from
changes in interest rates;42 and
Equity
risk, or risk arising from
fluctuations in stock values.43
Other
important categories of risk, such as operational, liquidity and systemic risk,
prove harder to quantify as they are less directly reflected by historical
market data. These forms of risk are defined as follows:
Operational
risk. Operational risk is a broad term that conveys risk
posed by a firms operations. The Basel II Accord defines operational risk as:
the risk of loss resulting from inadequate or failed internal processes,
people and systems or from external events.
Liquidity
risk: This risk takes two forms. Trading liquidity risk is
the risk that a firm cannot find a counterparty in the market willing to buy or
sell the asset at fair market value.45 Funding liquidity risk means the risk
that [a] firm will not be able to meet efficiently both expected and unexpected
current and future cash flow and collateral needs without affecting either
daily operations or the financial condition of the firm.
Systemic
risk: Systemic risk arises from a broader market failure;
this form of risk denotes potential losses that affect the entire market.
Other forms
of risk: Financial institutions also must manage other forms
of specialized risk, including concentration risk (potential losses to a lender
due to a high percentage of its total loans concentrated in a small number of
debtors),51 and reputation risk (potential losses stemming from a decline in
public opinion of the institution).52 Reputation risk also captures the
potential threat of bank runsP12-14
Nieuwe risicomodellen:
Simply
stated, value-at-risk describes the maximum possible loss over a specified time
period with a given level of confidence For example, a value-at-risk
determination of a maximum of $1,000,000 of losses over a two week period with
a 95% confidence interval translates into a 5% probability that losses will
exceed $1,000,000 over those two weeks. But, note that value-at-risk numbers
say nothing about the magnitude of losses above that confidence interval.58 In
the above example, there is a 5% chance of losses exceeding $1,000,000, but the
value-at-risk measurement does not specify how large those losses may be.P15
To calculate value-at-risk, modelers need to assume the
basic distribution of losses, i.e. they need to determine the shape of
the curve in the preceding diagram. They have three options P15
-normaalverdeing, may
have no basis in reality
-historical losses,
may have sample bias, markets do not always follow historical patterns
-monte carlo
simulations sophisticated random sampling driven by heavy computing power
-> requires assumptions about relationship among different variables in real
world market
One particular problem faced by value-at-risk models is fat
tails, or potential large magnitude, but low probability losses. P17
Stress testing involves changing model assumptions, such as
confidence level or the period of time measured, to see if value-at-risk
determinations change Modelers can also judge model performance through back
testing. This involves modelers making several hypothetical jumps back in
time, inputting into a model the historical data that was available at those
respective times, and then comparing the predictions of the model with how
losses actually unfolded P17
First, the models need to assess the risk of non-payment (i.e.
credit risk) on the underlying assets.91 To
accomplish this, these models require critical information from the originators
on the underlying assets. Given the sheer number and variety of underlying
assets, originators typically only provide to the sponsors of securitizations
certain categories of information. P26
In
many securitizations, rating agencies are paid by the SIV to issue credit
ratings of the asset-backed securities P28
rating agencies rely on the originators to provide
information on the underlying assets. P29
Internal Ratings-Based Approach that allows certain banks
to use internal models.P33
By giving banks the flexibility to adjust their regulatory
capital according to a mix of rating agency ratings and the respective banks
internal models, Basel II outsources significant regulatory authority to the
models of rating agencies and banks. P34
To be sure, the accord sets standards for when national
regulators may allow banks to use internal models and requires regulators to
audit those models.125 But, these lengthy standards give
bank regulators significant discretion in both deciding which banks qualify for
the privilege to use internal models auditing the models of those banks. P35
Bewijs dat basel II normen (nog bezig met implementatie) significant
lagere kapitaalvereisten opleveren :
After conducting a Quantitative Impact Study of the
prospective effects of the Internal Ratings-Based Approach, U.S. bank
regulators expressed concern that this new rule would dramatically lower
regulatory capital. See e.g., Pamela Martin, QIS
4: What Do the Numbers Really Mean?. RMA
J. (Sept. 1, 2005). See also Paul H. Kupiec, Capital Adequacy and Basel
II, FDIC Center for Financial Research
Working Paper No. 2004-02 (Dec. 2004) available at http://www.fdic.gov/bank/analytical/cfr/2004/wp2004/CFRWP_2004-02_Kupiec.pdf
Securities
issued in CDO are often resecuritized themselves, creating what is called a
CDO Squared.147 The iterative layering of securitizations of securitizations
of securitizations became wildly popular in financial markets.148 Similarly,
risks assumed in derivative transactions can themselves be hedged with other
derivatives.149 P42
Just as with a basic securitization or credit default
swap, modelers looking to measure the credit risk of the securities issued in a
CDO squared face high costs in identifying let alone finding information
about the credit risk posed by the numerous underlying mortgages and other
cash-producing assets that ultimately back the CDO P42 squared. These modelers again make simplifying assumptions,
such as relying on the credit ratings assigned to the securities immediately
prior in the securitization chain. Using rating agencies as an analytic
shortcut places a great deal of faith in the accuracy and integrity of those
ratings. P43
Henry T.C. Hu, Misunderstood Derivatives: the Causes of
Informational Failure and the Promise of Regulatory Incrementalism 1993
These
flaws fall into two broad categories: flaws in the technical design of the
models themselves, and flaws because of the skewed incentives of the parties
who select, implement and use those models. P50
Technical Flaws
Non-robust
assumptions, inadequate stress-and back testing
Flaws in Human Modelling Behaviour
->
individuals as rational actors
Spillover Effect
P54-56
Similarly, systemic risk can be
reduced effectively only if institutions throughout the financial system make
adequate risk management decisions. Otherwise, the system is susceptible to
domino effects as one institutional failure could cause cascading failures of
other firms due to counterparty and reputation risk. P65
Open source risk models ->
assumpties, algorithms & structures in the models
èpromoting transparency, auditable
ècounterparties could evaluate the adequacy
ècompetitors can check on financial institution
as well as on the regulators
èmany minds work on 1 thing
dangers ->
tendency towars homogeneity, more
systemic risk
but this is already the case, just
not possible to measure the degree of homogeneity (not disclosed models)
CRA Open source:
->license of SEC, so no problem
there
-> oligopoly positions
->ratings are used in many
regulations, like basel
II so there is a need for them
-> bad track records
-> assumptions and algorithms
should be shown
18-07-2009 om 23:21
geschreven door pieter
20-07-2009
Cantor & Packer 1997 - differences of opinion and selection bias in the credit rating industry
Samenvatting:
de verschillen in ratings die bureaus geven aan eenzelfde product zijn voornamelijk afkomstig van het feit dat hun ratingschalen (die meestal dezelfde layout hebben) andere indelingen kennen
Nuttige Stukken:
Although a number of other
credit rating agencies with a narrower focus operate in the United States,
DCR, Fitch, Moody's and S&P are the only agencies that rate US corporate
obligations across a broad industry spectrum. For example, Thomson Bankwatch
and IBCA (in the United States) exclusively rate financial institutions and
A.M. Best provides ratings on insurance companies' claims-paying abilities. P3
The
Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) currently designates only Moody's,
S&P, DCR, and Fitch as "nationally recognized statistical rating
organizations" (NRSROs) for rating all US corporate bond issues; 5 the
other regulators rely on the SEC's designations. P4
Many researchers have
documented that third, or optional, agencies on average assign higher ratings
than Moody's and S&P. Our results suggest that observed differences in
average ratings reflect differences in rating scales. They also call into question
financial industry regulations that assume equivalence of rating scales P22
We also explored why firms
choose to obtain additional ratings. We found that firms are more likely to
obtain a third rating if they are large and experienced issuers in the capital
market. However, there is little evidence that third agencies are employed
either to resolve ex ante uncertainty or to clear regulatory hurdles. While the
rating scales of third agencies may be higher than others, there is little
evidence that the decisions of issuers to use them are influenced by that
factor P22
20-07-2009 om 01:13
geschreven door pieter
Stolper 2009 - Regulation of Credit Rating Agencies
Samenvatting:
de verhouding tss CRA's en de regulerende overheden is een principal-agent relatie. Er bestaat een werkwijze van de overheden die voorkomt dat rating agencies samenwerken om verhoogde ratings af te leveren en ze motiveert om correct te werken.
Nuttige Stukken:
This paper studies a repeated principal-agent problem in which a
regulator approves credit rating agencies. While credit rating agencies can
observe an issuers type, the regulator cannot. Credit rating agencies offer
each issuer a rating and are paid by the issuerswho demand a rating. The regulator cannot
observe whether a credit rating agency assigns correct ratings. The regulator
can only observe the default rate within a rating category for each credit
rating agency. The default rate within a rating category does not only depend
on whether a credit rating agency assigns correct ratings. The default rate can
also be influenced by a common shock. P1
The model shows that there exists an approval scheme which can
induce credit rating agencies to offer correct ratings. The model suggests that
a regulator should both deter a credit rating agency from unilaterally offering
inflated ratings, and provide an incentive to deviate from a collusive
agreement to offer inflated ratings. The model indicates that a regulator
should both threaten to deny approval in future periods if a credit rating
agencys performance is worse than its competitors, and reward a credit rating
agency which deviates from a collusive agreement to offer inflated ratings by
reducing the number of approved credit rating agencies in future periods. P5
20-07-2009 om 15:29
geschreven door pieter
Kuhner 2001 - Financial Rating Agencies - Are They Credible
Samenvatting:
...
Nuttige Stukken:
The paper asks if credit rating
agencies have incentives to misrepresent their clients
credit quality during an ongoing
systemic crisis. Two important elements are essential for
a systemic crisis: (1) Investors are
not able to distinguish fundamentally healthy debtors
from fundamentally unhealthy ones.
(2) Investors tend to cumulatively withdraw their
funds. Therefore, neither
fundamentally healthy nor unhealthy debtors can be expected to
survive a
creditors exit. P1
Their goal is to overcome asymmetric information
between
both market sides by evaluating financial claims
according to standardized quality
categories P1
The agencies most important
job is the evaluation of fixed income securities. P2
rating agencies emphasize that their evaluation is,
after
all, their subjective opinion, which is not verifiable
by courts4. Also, damages due
to obvious rating errors are not part of the rating
contract and not currently
enforceable by litigation5. P2
ðenkel reputatie
staat in voor kwaliteit
P3 -> allerlei argumenten
tegen rating agencies
Procyclical bias: Especially in the aftermath of the Southeast Asian
crisis in
1997/1998, agencies were blamed for behaving
procyclically, i.e. for simply following
the majority opinion of market participants13: According to
many
observers, the agencies did not give any warning
signals until after the turbulence
in the Asian markets had begun. However, when the
crisis was actually
spreading, the agencies reacted by cumulatively
downgrading issuers invested
in the Southeast-Asian markets without taking in
account individual portfolio
quality14. P3
Voor de
rest was deze paper te moeilijk!
20-07-2009 om 15:30
geschreven door pieter
Nomura - Fixed Income Research 16/2/2006 - Rating Shopping, now the consequences
Rating Shopping
Defined: Rating shopping occurs when an issuer chooses the rating agency that will assign the highest rating or that has the most lax criteria for achieving a desired rating. Rating shopping rarely involves corporate, sovereign, and municipal bonds. However, it is common for securitization issues.
S&P's Criteria Change: S&P's old criteria for rating CDO's backed by corporate debt included a modeling assumption of zero correlation between companies in different industries.2 That assumption was very lenient and often allowed CDO issuers to achieve their target rating levels with less credit enhancement than the other rating agencies would have required.
=> veel kritiek, alle andere ratingbureaus kwamen met empirisch bewijs dat dat geen nul kon zijn -> S&P verhoogt inter industry correlation van 0 naar 5% => 35 tranches kregen plots negative implications
Conclusion: The implications are reasonably clear. An investor seeking rating stability generally should favor multiple-rated deals. Deals that carry multiple ratings are less likely to carry significant migration risk associated with rating shopping. However, an investor should expect to give up some increment of yield to get securities that carry multiple ratings.
20-07-2009 om 15:37
geschreven door pieter
22-07-2009
BIS working paper no209: FAIR VALUE ACCOUNTING FOR FINANCIAL INSTRUMENTS: SOME IMPLEMENTATIONS FOR BANK REGULATION (August 2006)
Samenvatting:
Zowel de FASB als de IASB hebben de laatste jaren standaarden ingevoerd die er op wijzen dat men stelselmatig naar full fair value voor financial instruments wil streven. Intussen gaat dit al niet meer door, dixit de IASB!
Een van de onderzoeksresultaten is: Second, they need to consider more broadly how best to minimise measurement error in fair values so as to maximise their usefulness to investors and creditors as they make their investment decisions, and how best to ensure bank managers have incentives to select those. Om minder measurement errorste hebben past de IASB sinds kort die level-hierarchy toe, maar die stond reeds in FASB exposure draft in 2005! Dus of het effectief zal zijn is maar de vraag natuurlijk...
Market to market implementation issues
Marking-to-market financial instruments are relatively easy if they are actively traded in liquid markets. The problem becomes more complicated if active markets do not exist, particularly if the financial instrument is a compound instrument comprising several embedded option-like features, values for which depend on inter-related default and price risk characteristics. Moreover, Barth and Landsman (1995) makes the observation that in the absence of active, liquid markets, fair value is not well defined in the sense that an instruments acquisition price, selling price, and value-in-use to the entity can differ from each other.13 Stated another way, even if an instruments acquisition or selling prices are observable, these prices can only, at best, provide upper or lower bounds on its fair value. The FASBs stated preference for using an instruments selling price as its measure of fair value is appropriate when fair value is well defined, but is somewhat arbitrary when it is not.
Dus in 1995 is er reeds een paper verschenen die vragen stelt bij het gebruik van fair value in illiquide markten.
Voor de rest gaat de paper vooral over waarom men fair value al dan niet een goede maatstaf is om te meten. Dit is eigenlijk irrelevant voor de thesis, aangezien we fair value als een gegeven beschouwen. De dingen die hierboven staan kunnen wel interessant zijn.
22-07-2009 om 12:06
geschreven door pieter
FEP working papers: the transition to IFRS: disclosures by portuguese listed companies ( august 2008)
Deze paper gaat hoofdzakelijk over de transitie van Portguese GAAP naar IFRS, en dit niet specifiek voor de banksector. Minder interessante paper dus.
Wat wel interessant is: de conservatism index die ze gebruiken om GAAP conservatief gedrag te vergelijken met IFRS. (vanaf p. 16)
Op p.17 staat er een formule die men gebruikt om 'conservatism' te meten. Deze komt uit:
Gray, S. J. (1980), "The impact of International Accounting Differences from a Security-Analysis Perspective: Some European Evidence", Journal of Accounting Research, Vol. 18, 1, pp. 64-76.
We kunnen deze formule misschien toepassen op het verschil tussen IFRS en onderliggend resultaat bij banken, vanaf 2006 bekeken. Wel met de bedenking dat de formule voorzien is voor een hele lijst van ondernemingen binnen een land (niet alleen de banksector). Maar het kan interessant zijn aangezien een groot deel van de verliezen van KBC (en waarschijnlijk ook Dexia) te wijten zal zijn aan IFRS voor financial instruments.
Ook zeker nog te lezen:
Jermakowicz, E. (2004), "Effects of Adoption of International Financial Reporting Standards in Belgium: The Evidence from BEL-20 Companies", Accounting in Europe, Vol. 1, September, pp. 51-70. Jones, T. and R. Luther (2005),